Let the kids cycle

Abstract: Improving levels of walking and cycling is critically important for the nation’s health and wealth.  This article explores the reasons why focusing on working with children and schools to enable cycling in particular is likely to yield the best results for mode shift, by looking at behaviour change models as well as  what is known about human travel behaviour.



It is critically important that we allow more people to choose to travel by walking and cycling.  This is for a number of reasons:

More walking and cycling tackles all of these issues at once. Walking and cycling are also, fairly uniquely, in both the individual’s interest to participate in (saving money, faster travel, better health) and in the Government’s interest for individuals to participate in (reduced expenditure, improved population health, greater productivity from the population).


Why focus on cycling?

Looking at the walking environment in the UK, it is clear that walking is an accessible option for many, at least for short journeys – although there are problems caused by the volumes of motor traffic (i.e. crossing times, noise and pollution making for an unpleasant walking environment).  Cycling, on the other hand, provides a viable option for many more journeys by allowing for greater distances to be covered; shorter journey times and larger carrying capacity.

But cycling is not currently viewed as a viable mode of transport by many; mainly due to fear of motor traffic associated with lack of fit-for-purpose provision for cycling. It is my view that in general, the things which facilitate cycling also help to reduce motor traffic volumes, therefore improving the walkability of an area in the long run. The same argument applies to good public transport – however, this is provided at much greater expense to the state.  We should therefore be prioritising cycling as the area for greatest potential gains.

It is clear that one of the features that stands out about cycling cultures is that there is a great emphasis on allowing and encouraging children to cycle. In the Netherlands, the Fietserbond (Cyclists’ Union) go into schools to deliver cycle skills training, and new schools are designed in such a way that they are away from roads; encouraging walking and cycling.  The Danish Cycling Embassy are keen to focus on the importance of encouraging children to cycle.    


Overcome the barriers to entry early

Beyond the immediate environment, there are a number of skill and knowledge based barriers to cycling.  Potential utility bike riders need to know: how to ride a bike; where to go to get bike repairs; where to go to buy a bike; what sort of bike is likely to be practical for them; how to plan routes to where they want to go; how to manage traffic whilst riding (even in the Netherlands, cyclists must mix with low levels of low speed traffic on occasion); how to carry a passenger; how to secure a bike so that it won’t get stolen.

Helping children overcome these barriers means that not only are they more likely to be able to cycle as children – but they will turn into adults with cycling as a practical choice, without these barriers to overcome.


Humans are habit-forming creatures

The reason why there is sometimes a gap between what seems rational in terms of behaviour and what we actually do, is habit. It seems likely to me that as decision making is hard, and uses limited resources, humans tend to use strategies to minimise the need for this.

Habit or routine is one such strategy. Rather than re-think every single decision every single day, we take a decision once, and then just re-use that decision. I think this is why we find starting a new job, a new school, or even using a new mode of transport so exhausting – because we’re having to make many ‘new decisions’.

Some people take habit to extremes – for example, Mark Zuckerberg buys multiples of the same clothes, and generally wears the same outfit every day to minimise energy spent on ‘frivolous’ decisions.  I’m not sure this is rational for everyone however, as appearances do count for most of us, most of the time – this might be especially true if you’re from a poorer background.

If we are minimising new choices, then it is logical to think that we will use modes of transport that we are most familiar with. This is borne out by what we see in travel choices of individuals, with previous travel behaviours often carried forward when circumstances change. For example, immigrants living in the Netherlands are more likely to cycle than people in their home country, but still significantly less likely to cycle than those born in the Netherlands.

My personal experience bears this out (anecdote alert!) – on moving from the country where driving had quite a lot going for it, to London where it didn’t, I continued driving for most journeys until a budgetary crisis forced a rethink and ‘eureka’ moment of realising that cycling was, for me as someone who had learned to cycle on the road as a child, much faster and much more efficient than driving  as well as saving me a shed-load of cash and allowing him to go on holidays again (even if recently these ‘holidays’ mostly ended up turning into field trips exploring and trying to understand what has underpinned development of cycling cultures in places such as the Netherlands, Denmark, parts of Switzerland, parts of the US etc…).

Making sure that children have a habit of cycling for at least some of their journeys, then, is likely to lead a higher adult cycling population.  It should be noted I am saying ‘this is likely’ because it is surprisingly difficult to find direct, thorough research on this effect – please do comment below if you manage to find any!


Parents and carers are likely to be more open to changing travel behaviour than other adults

Working with children doesn’t just benefit the children themselves. Children have parents, and often a network of carers (family and friends) who also have an incentive to want to join in with cycling that the children may be doing – if the child is enjoying something, they want to be part of that.  Not only this, but behaviour change models suggest that we tend to be most open to changing our behaviour when we change something in our routines. Children are constantly changing routines, and causing change in their carer’s routines too – changing schools, a new after-school club, all these result in carers having to re-think their travel routines.  These continual transition states provide a great opportunity to get the carers involved in cycling too.


Best practise design for allowing kids to cycle is best practise for everyone

Children have smaller legs than adults and therefore have the greatest need for direct routes that minimise gradients and stopping; they also have the greatest need for both subjective and objective safety, with forgiving design allowing for mistakes.  These attributes are also the attributes that make for the most attractive cycling routes for adults too – faster routes that feel, and are, safe.



Working to enable more children to cycle not only has huge benefits for children directly empowered to cycle, but also has a disproportionate benefit in terms of enabling more travel by bike in general. The children directly empowered are likely to choose cycling as a mode choice throughout their life (ie 60-70 years of benefit from the behaviour change effort), but they are also likely to encourage parents and carers, who are more likely than other adults to reconsider their travel options and therefore take up cycling.


Conflict of interest statement: I work in local authorities on a range of projects which are all at least partly aimed at allowing children to use bikes for useful journeys.



Filed under Uncategorized

What’s the impact on total CO2 emissions of electric cars or – are they really fossil fuelled?

The recent Volkswagen Diesel scandal has resulted in renewed debate around electric vehicles (EVs) and encouraged me to give some more thought to my feelings on them.

As usual I am interested in their use from a benefits to society/transport planning perspective rather than an individual consumer perspective – it may make perfect sense for individuals to get an EV depending on their circumstances.  However, while I consider that they may be a fix to significantly reduce air pollution in cities (although at least one, extremely thorough, study suggests that this is not clear cut, with some places in the US getting a disbenefit from electric car use in terms of air pollution) – they leave the host of other problems that come with motor vehicles including road danger, noise (most noise from motor vehicles being associated with tyres or the vehicle moving through the air, rather than engine noise), the road space requirements for them splitting communities and fail to deliver the exercise benefits of active travel – or public transport which frequently involves at least some active travel in every journey.  In addition to this, a large chunk of the particulates associated with motor vehicle usage actually come from wear and tear on tyres/brakes – these particulate emissions will remain whatever method propels the vehicle.

I am specifically interested in whether EVs will reduce carbon footprints over conventional vehicles.  If a government is worried about climate change, does it make sense to invest time, money and effort into promoting their use?

Other Analysis:

A quick dive into the available literature brings up a few different sets of analysis.  It seems that how effective they are at reducing (or not) CO2 emissions relative to conventionally powered motor vehicles is highly sensitive to the source of the electricity powering the EV.  What is interesting about all of the analysis I found is that it all assumes that adding an extra load on the electricity grid does not change the mix of electrical supply.  i.e. an increase in demand from electric cars increases the amount of renewable energy or efficiency of electricity production – on which more later.

Here’s a particularly clear graph which popped up, from this article here:

Screen Shot 2015-09-30 at 22.12.22

They also put together a neat little graph, re-scaling this into MPG equivalent which seems more intuitive to me.  On this scale, a petrol car which can achieve better than 30mpg is a better choice for reducing CO2 emissions than an electric car from a coal-heavy electricity mix.  The best modern petrol cars, when driven in an efficient manner, can deliver double this!


According to this type of analysis, in the countries with the highest proportion of their electricity from renewables, it appears that an EV will beat a petrol car several times over.  In the UK, an efficient petrol or diesel car will just about beat an EV.  However, I think there are problems with using this type of analysis as it is based on a key assumption which I think is incorrect.

A Challenge to Previous Available Analysis

This analysis, and all the rest of the analysis that I could find in the time available to me for research are all based on the assumption that drawing more electricity from the grid does not change the supply mix.  When we look at the total supply of energy for the UK provided by the National Grid, it comes to a total of about 27.3 million tons of oil equivalents.  This compares with total demand for energy by the UK road network of 40 million tons of oil equivalent.  If we assume that most fuel is burnt on longer journeys which are not practical for EVs; and that we can only realistically aim for 1/8th of this energy usage being converted to electric vehicles, the additional demand on the grid is some 5 million tons of oil equivalent.

I do not know for certain, but it seems highly unlikely to me that adding this amount of energy demand on the national grid will have no effect on the energy mix.  Although there are complications around usage of pumped hydro to store electrical energy, and efficiency of power stations under sub-maximal loads, what seems most likely to me overall is that renewable sources (with 0 fuel cost, but high installation costs) get used first, and then fossil fuels are used to top this up (because the majority of the cost of these is in the consumption of the fuel, rather than in the construction of the facility).  This seems to be supported by the fact that it is reported that the electricity mix at night, when consumption is lower, has a higher proportion from renewable sources.

If this is the case, then any extra load on the grid over and above the current usage, will result in more fossil fuels being used.  Does it not seem reasonable to assume, therefore, that the extra electrical energy needed to fuel EV’s will come from fossil fuels?

If this is the case then extra EVs adding extra load on the national grid can be thought of as being fossil fuelled, resulting in them being far less efficient in terms of CO2 emissions than more efficient petrol or diesel cars once transmission and generation losses are accounted for.


  1. If we look back at the data above, it seems clear that *if my assumptions are correct*, that EVs produce many times more CO2 equivalent emissions than an efficient petrol vehicle, undermining the case for subsidising and promoting the use of these vehicles.
  2. It seems that until we have a surplus of renewable energy that this will remain the case.  A government interested in reducing the country’s carbon footprint should prioritise de-carbonising the grid over the use of electrical cars
  3. Although not the focus of this article, this argument has implications for individuals who may be interested in buying an electric car to try and reduce their carbon footprint (hint: you may be better off investing elsewhere – e.g. in solar panels or a wind turbine for your house)

Does anyone have any expertise on how the national grid works that might challenge or support the assumptions that I have made above?  Please do comment if so.


Filed under Uncategorized

Road safety versus saving lives

I know you’re all thinking it – how can there be conflict between road safety and saving lives?

Much of the dialogue about cycling infrastructure refers to safety.  I argue here that the problem is overwhelmingly not safety as such, but that the problem is that people are not cycling and the priority of cycle infrastructure should be to tackle this first and foremost.  Sometimes this does not mean picking the ‘safest’ designs if it brings about undue delay that deters cycling.  The same applies to walking.  However, it should be pointed out that the perception of a lack of safety is the main reason that people do not cycle and tackling this is key – it should be clear that, as the Cycle Embassy of Great Britain point out, fear and genuine danger do not always go together, as illustrated by roller coasters.

Transport related deaths in the UK in a typical year:

Cycling – 118 (2012)

Walking – 420 (2012)

All road deaths – 1,754 (2012)

Air pollution – 28,000 (note – this only includes deaths from PM2.5 particulates, excluding NOx and other pollutants – the total death toll is likely at least double this)

Inactivity – 96,000 (estimates vary – I have argued in the past that current estimates are far too low and that the true number of inactivity related deaths is likely to be in the region of 200,000 deaths due to systematic errors with how these estimates are obtained; but let’s stick with peer reviewed numbers and quote Lee et al)

We can see from this data that relatively few people die cycling or walking; many people die because of not walking or cycling (from inactivity) or as a result of excessive use of motor vehicles (from air pollution).  It should be clear that it is not possible to be inactive if walking or cycling make up a reasonable portion of your travel and you wish to have any kind of work or social life.  The vast majority of air pollution is caused by motor vehicles, and this pollution has the greatest effect as high population areas tend to have the highest levels of motor traffic.

Total deaths while walking or cycling: 538

Total deaths due to low levels of walking and cycling: 124,000 (note: likely a low-end estimate)

We can see that there is an urgent need to increase the levels of walking and cycling and reduce motor travel to reduce inactivity and air pollution deaths.  However, I also argue that mode shift itself is likely to reduce road deaths overall in any case.  Why?  Well, very few people die on our roads without a motor vehicle involved.  To me, it seems self-evident that reducing motor traffic’s dominance on the road will reduce the high speeds which result in collisions being fatal, but also reducing the number of motor vehicles reduces the number of opportunities for fatal or serious collisions, all other things being equal.  There is also a large volume of evidence for something called the ‘Safety in Numbers’ effect – more people on bikes provides a protective effect for others on bikes as those in motor vehicles become more used to looking out for them and predicting their behaviour.

What is implicit in the numbers above is that where there is a conflict between safety and encouraging mode shift, mode shift takes precedence because many more people are killed by a lack of cycling and walking – by at least 2 orders of magnitude – than cycling and walking.  

How can we bring about this mode shift?  The evidence is clear that the major barriers to people walking and cycling is a perception of danger, and because they do not feel they have enough time to walk or cycle to their destinations.  I suspect that part of the reason that infrastructure has been ignored for so long in getting people cycling is that if you ask people why they don’t cycle now if they want to, that they will often say “it’s too far” when really they mean that the cycle infrastructure is substandard, slow and inconvenient, which makes it too far.

I do not believe that simply telling people that cycling is statistically safe is likely to result in significant mode shift.   Real changes are needed to the streets to achieve this along the Dutch/Danish/New York/Barcelona/Seville/Munich model which has proven to be successful in mode shift. It should be clear that almost always those things which encourage more cycling are likely to improve safety too – as tackling subjective safety is likely to improve real safety.  However, there are certain situations where there may be conflicts between safety and directness and convenience.

Where might there be conflicts between mode shift and safety? I have seen it suggested that cycle priority crossings over roads are more dangerous than where those cycling give way to motor traffic.  This is an example where in most circumstances, unless there is an extremely large difference in risk, the trade off with speed means that you reduce deaths the most by prioritising cycle crossings because mode shift trumps nominal safety.

There are also implications at junctions.  For example, installing a ‘hold the left turn’ junction may be the gold standard for preventing left-hooks at junctions; but if this pushes the cycle time up for that junction, imposing more delay, the safety benefit may be outweighed by a small decrease in mode share of cycling due to extra wait time.

To summarise:

1. Transport related deaths due to air pollution and inactivity outweigh those caused by collisions by at least 2 orders of magnitude

2. This means that careful consideration needs to be given to any trade-off between those features of a cycle or walking network that improve safety on the road at the cost of slowing speed of progress of those walking or cycling, because this may have implications for the degree of mode-shift – but of course bearing in mind that a feeling of fear is one of – if not the – major deterrent to people walking and cycling more


Filed under Uncategorized

A rational choice

There’s a lot of misunderstanding about why people cycle.  Often, the assumption seems to be that those that cycle do it for noble  reasons – because it’s good for the environment or good for reducing air pollution; other times it seems to be perceived as something that people do because of other, social, benefits – e.g. to fit in with a group of friends or because it’s something you’ve always done as a habit.


Understanding the reasons for people cycling help us to know how we can encourage people to cycle more.  If we think that the reasons are environmental, then we can highlight this fact – but I have to be honest, I think that consideration of the environment rarely figures, apart from as a tie-breaker when two modes of transport are very close, when it comes to making decisions on how we travel.


For me, and I suspect for most others that cycle, it’s just the rational choice.  Let’s take a look at my transport options as a case study:


Drive (this always used to be my primary mode of transport, even once I moved to London in 2007):

Money: £4,500/year for all transport

Time for my current commute (Roehampton – King’s Cross): 60 minutes each way, 120 minutes a day (assuming no major traffic-trauma or parking-related issues).


Public Transport: 

Money: £1,472  zone 1-3 travelcard; plus assume £500 for other train travel – £1,972

Time for my current commute: 70 minutes each way, 140 minutes a day



Money: £2,000 (includes all bike expenses plus train travel where bike not practical)

Time for my current commute: 35 minutes each way, 75 minutes each day (I have excluded shower time in the morning as I would shower in the morning in any case – but have included 5 minutes for the extra shower I tend to have at the end of the day).



Money: assume a £60 pair of walking shoes every 3 months = £240

Time for my current commute: 180 minutes each way; 360 minutes a day


Given that I’d be walking 6 hours a day, I think I’ll discount walking! (although I did walk it for one day on walk to work week, it wasn’t very practical for a journey of this length)


So far, it looks like the bike just skims it, doesn’t it?  But wait a minute – if I cycle, do I need to go the gym any more?  No.  We know that the best health outcomes come from 300+ minutes exercise a week – so let’s assume I only really need an hour of exercise a day, five days a week.  I don’t need to pay the £40/month gym fees either.


How does it look now then?


Bike (adjusted for no need to go to gym):

Money: £2,000 – £600 gym fees = £1,400

Time for my current commute: 75 minutes – 60 minutes exercise time = 15 minutes


So in a typical year, when I compare against when I used to drive, I’m saving £3,100 a year; and saving nearly 2 hours EVERY DAY.  Even compared to public transport I’m still saving enough to pay for a long weekend away each year and 2 hours a day – compared to a car, I’m saving enough for a 3 week holiday!


Cycling is for me, the only rational choice, and that is why I cycle.  Even if I were deeply unfit – say I could only cycle at half the speed – I would still be saving time; but in addition, if I were that unfit the cycling would be adding years to my life – an average person gains an hour of life for every hour cycling.  Given 2 hours plus exercise a day, I wouldn’t stay unfit very long either – I’d get fitter and faster.


I’d guess that for most people cycling, the same is true – they aren’t trying to save the planet, they just value their time and money!

Leave a comment

Filed under Uncategorized

What’s the real UK death toll from inactivity? Part two – how many?

In part one of this series I looked at why a lack of exercise causes premature deaths; the aim of this second part is to take a look at exactly how many people may be dying from a lack of exercise. My analysis shows that this number is very high, but it also seems that the studies that I found were underestimating the true death toll due to systematically conservative assumptions in approximations used.


The studies:

The HIPI model, based on Lee et al (http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0140673612610319), predicts a death toll of 36,815 people a year in England, for ages 40-79, but only from coronary heart disease, colorectal cancer, breast cancer and diabetes.   This has a few conservative assumptions from my point of view: I think people start to die of inactivity from childhood (though admittedly in far lower numbers); it ignores many illnesses thought to be caused by inactivity; it uses guideline minimum amounts of exercise (150 minutes) as its baseline for active, and it doesn’t take in the whole of the UK (to allow us to compare to other equivalent statistics).

To correct the last point, we can make an approximation by taking into account the population size of England as compared to the UK, assume that the populations show similar behaviour, and arrive at an estimate of about 44,000 deaths per year in the UK. Of course, this still leaves the other issues – so let’s go back to look at the underlying study – Lee et al.


Lee et al quote an all-cause mortality burden of 16.9% of all deaths in the UK – with a total death toll of about 569,000 per year from the ONS, this yields 96,000 deaths per year. Again, they are assuming that active people are doing guideline amounts of exercise (i.e. over 150 minutes); they also assumed that only people over the age of 40 suffered increased mortality rates. These are two flaws which lead me to expect that this is an underestimate.


Whats the issue with current thinking?

Most biological systems deliver a dose response curve that looks a bit like this:


Basically, initially as we increase dose, you get maximal response up until a point (corresponding to about 20M/L of the drug in the graph above) where the effect of each additional dose decreases. Of course, in the case of exercise, the units of our dose will be measured in calories, minutes of activity or some measure that accounts for volume and intensity of exercise.

The above studies use models for calculating the death toll from inactivity assume that somewhere in the region of 150 minutes of exercise a week (the UK guidelines) deliver almost all of the benefit that exercise can bring. This is based on the dea that 150 minutes is at the ‘plateau’ stage of the above curve – where an increase in dose will be a small, or no, further improvement in health outcomes. I believe that this is not true, and in fact the Lee et al study in the Lancet does acknowledge this as a limitation in their estimates. A large meta-analysis (a review of available evidence) (http://ije.oxfordjournals.org/content/early/2011/09/05/ije.dyr112 ) gives an estimate of a 14% reduction of deaths at 150 minutes of exercise, and 26% – nearly double – at 300 minutes.

In fact we repeatedly find (http://www.indiana.edu/~k562/articles/role/Lee%20PA%20morbidity.pdf, http://www.thelancet.com/journals/lancet/article/PIIS0140-6736(11)60749-6/fulltext ) that in fact, over the range of durations studied, there appears to be an linear relationship between volume of exercise and decreased mortality rates – i.e. a doubling of exercise volume doubles the protective of effect of exercise.

It feels intuitively as if there must come a point where increasing exercise volumes do not keep on reducing death rates per year – but it seems from the studies reviewed that we have not reached that point at 300 minutes, let alone 150!

We can draw a dose-response curve for exercise using currently available data, in fact someone has already done this for me using data from one study:




It seems moderate exercise for various activities yields about 250 calories per 30 minutes; so it looks like we’re reaching the point where the benefits of exercise start slowing at about 2,500 calories exercise per week – or 10 x 30 minutes of exercise a week – 300 minutes (warning – fast and dirty approximation!).  Note that it appears that the benefits are still accruing, albeit more slowly, at 3000 Kcal per week.

Interestingly, there seems to be no lower threshold for exercise effectiveness (so there’s no flat spot at the start of the graph) – basically any amount will start improving your health.


So: how many?

The evidence above seem to show that best available protection from deaths by exercise comes at more than 300 minutes of exercise a week. The studies investigated above are based on 150 minutes – which seem to show about half the level of benefit of 300 minutes.

This means that the benefit to those individuals doing less than 150 minutes can be expected to double – but this isn’t the only effect. There will be a fair chunk of the population that were considered ‘active’ under previous studies but who are doing less than 300 minutes of activity a week, and these will also benefit from doing more exercise. This leads me to suggest that the studies above are underestimating the possible protective effect of exercise by at least a factor of 2.

Applying a factor of 2 to Lee et al gives a death toll from inactivity, UK-wide, of 192,000 deaths per year. Note, this is a very fast and dirty estimate and needs further investigation, but can be expected to be a low-end estimate as I have ignored the benefit to those individuals doing between 150 and 300 minutes of exercise a week for simplicity.  I have ignored the number from the HIPI model, as it is based on the same underlying data, but is clearly ignoring a vast swathe of deaths caused by inactivity from the discrepency with the number generated by Lee et al.

This puts inactivity as a cause of death ahead of smoking (100,000 deaths per year in the UK, from here: http://ash.org.uk/files/documents/ASH_107.pdf); vastly exceeds deaths directly caused by air pollution from combustion emissions (19,000 from here: http://pubs.acs.org/doi/abs/10.1021/es2040416); and absolutely dwarfs deaths from road traffic collisions (1,754 deaths in 2012).


Notes of caution:

These calculations are based on correlation studies – i.e. they look at how much less likely someone who exercises at different amounts is to die than someone who’s inactive; however, as discussed in other blogs correlation does not always imply causation and there may be confounding factors around more affluent people being more likely to exercise.   As affluent people generally live longer, it may be that this is causing the apparent protective effect of exercise. However, there are also other confounders – the types of exercise participated in may expose people to greater risk of dying from other factors – e.g. air pollution from exercising outside. These confounders may cause this study to underestimate the true protective effect of exercise if, say, you were exercising in the country where this air pollution was not present in such high quantities.



  1. It seems highly likely that any amount of exercise will improve your chance of living a long life – and the more exercise you do, the greater the benefit, until at least 300 minutes of moderate-to-intense activity per week
  2. Guideline amounts of activity are below the optimum amounts for reducing avoidable deaths according to best available data
  3. Available studies seem to be underestimating death rates from inactivity by a large amount, possibly a factor of greater than 2
  4. The reason for these underestimates is an assumption that guideline amounts of activity deliver all possible health benefits from exercise
  5. Applying a correction factor to Lee et al predicts a death toll from inactivity of 192,000 deaths per year – this is likely to still be a conservative estimate, and most likely puts inactivity as the leading cause of avoidable death in the UK by some considerable margin
  6. More research is needed in the field to fully quantify the likely death toll, the economic cost to the state and therefore how much needs to be invested in preventing inactivity through clever urban design and sports and physical activity interventions








Filed under Uncategorized

What’s the real UK death toll from inactivity? Part one – How?

What’s it got to do with movement?

This  post is the first in a two-part series aimed at looking at the true cost of inactivity in the UK in number of lives lost.  Why, this being a transport based blog?  Well, I believe that there is strong evidence that the built environment has a direct effect on peoples health.  We know that exercise is well correlated with lower mortality rates (e.g. meta-analysis (review of research done) here).  In fact, we see that the least fit 25% have mortality rates have four times that of the most fit 25%.  We see this pattern over and over again.  We also know that the number one cause of people not exercising is that people feel that they do not have time to exercise.  The answer, to me, seems to be that we need to help people fit more exercise into their day in time where they would otherwise be sedentary.  This could include more movement at work for some; but with people spending an average of 1 hour every day travelling, I argue that commute/travel time is the obvious candidate for fitting in more exercise.  Often, journeys could be moved at least partly to active travel modes with either a trivial increase in travel time, or often, a reduction in travel times once the quickest route has been worked out, some fitness has been gained and most appropriate equipment sourced.  There is strong evidence from Denmark that cycling to work reduces mortality (your chance of dying in any given year) by 28% once other factors (diet, economic group, other physical activity) are adjusted for  (from this study here).

How does exercise save lives?

Well, we know it prevents heart disease, reduces levels of certain types of cancer; this is a matter of scientific record.  But I think it goes further than that.  I would suggest that being fit, which leads on from exercising, has many other benefits when it comes to staying alive.  Sure, more cycling might increase your chance of being involved in an accident by some small measure over sitting in a train or driving for the same length journey, but it seems reasonable to suggest that your chances of surviving an accident as a fit person are significantly higher – you can control a fall better, and your better developed musculature, tendons and bone structure   will help reduce your chances of death in the event of an accident.  Suicide is the main cause of death amongst 5-34 year olds, and there’s some evidence that physical activity helps fight the depression that leads to it.

What if you still have a fall, a heart attack, or cancer?  Well, my opinion (as distinct from direct scientific research that I can access) is this.  The thing that finally kills you is you no longer being able to pump oxygenated blood round your body.  If you are fit you have more blood, bigger usable lung area, a bigger heart, and better developed blood vessels, then when the crisis comes you can stay alive for longer, giving your body a longer window to sort out the problem, or the magic of modern medicine longer to save you.  Even things as small as doctors being able to take blood samples to find out more about what’s making you ill – because you have bigger veins from exercising more (established long enough that it’s hard to find the studies online, but e.g. here: http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/12640286) – can be expected to be significant (is significant, according to doctors that I’ve spoken to).

Beyond the death toll..

There is also the reduction in quality of life that comes with being less fit: regular exercise cuts the risk of dementia in old age by nearly 2/3; reduces the effects of type 2 diabetes and the chances of being affected by it in the first place by over 50%; there even more immediate short term effects, with reduction in obesity, most obviously, but also brings benefits as wide as increases in intelligence (certainly in children).

The scale of the problem

This all sounds very serious what with all this talk of death, dementia, and diabetes; but I don’t see it that way – I see a massive opportunity to give many people longer, more productive lives with less ill health and disability.  In part two of this blog I will explain why I think that it is possible that as many as A THIRD of all deaths in the UK – nearly 200,000 deaths per year – may be premature deaths which exercise would prevent.  Many of these deaths could be prevented by clever urban design which gives people the opportunity to exercise on a daily basis.  This is higher than previous analysis that I’ve found, but I think I have a strong case that is worth considering.


Filed under Uncategorized

Safety in Numbers – Correlation or Causation?

Correlation does not always equal causation

In a past life, I trained as a Scientist (a Chemist) and I’ve always been drawn to analysis of data. The son of a Pharmaceutical Researcher and a Public Health professional, I was brought up with “correlation =/= causation”. Sometimes, though, you have to say that a correlation is so strong, and seen so repeatedly in so many different circumstances independent of other factors that the link is almost certainly causative. Despite what people may tell you, science is never certain about anything – the scientific method means that something is always open to being disproved – e.g. the speed of light being the ‘fundamental speed limit’ is still open to being challenged by stray Neutrino’s travelling faster.  So it isn’t possible to say anything ‘for certain’, but here’s a great case study for you.

Safety in numbers (S/N)

I blogged about this here, but my argument was a bit weak and incomplete. I intend here to show the full weight of the argument, and why I think that S/N is ‘the real deal’ – by which I mean that, all other things being equal, more cycling will improve the safety per cyclist.

What is ‘Safety in Numbers’?

S/N is the idea that as you increase the numbers of a group of road users on the road (cyclists or pedestrians), that the safety per person using that mode improves – i.e. if you double the number of people cycling, you do not double the number of accidents – the number of accidents either rise very slightly, stay stable, or counter-intuitively, fall. I am most interested here in looking at the case for S/N in cycling as this is the evidence I’m most familiar with, and it’s easier just to use one example to keep the blog concise.

How does it work?

There are a number of possible mechanisms for S/N; it could be that increased numbers mean that other road users are more used to looking out for the more common road users and anticipating their movements; it could be because the infrastructure is built to better cater for the more common road users; finally, it could be that more people cycling, or walking, means less cars and therefore less interactions which could lead to a collision of enough severity to be recorded.

The evidence:

NB – it should be noted that there is a general trend of falling death rates on our roads, as we learn to keep people alive better and cars become more collision friendly.  The data below should be seen in that light.

1. Cycling in 14 European Countries, 1998:


There is a clear relationship here, showing that those countries with the highest levels of cycling have the lowest numbers of fatalaties per 100,000,000 km.

2.  Levels of cycling against fatality rates – UK 1950-99

Cycling in UK 50-99

a)  Between 1950-52, cycling levels rose and fatality rates fell

b) Between 1952-1972 there’s a pretty clear relationship showing that less cycling correlates with higher fatality rates.

c) Between 1973 and 1999 fatality rates fell despite cycling levels remaining roughly constant – I believe this to show a marked improvement in our ability to keep people alive, as a similar effect is seen in driving accidents.

3. Levels of cycling against fatality rates – Netherlands 1980-99

Cycling in NL 1980-98

It’s commonly thought that cycling was always common in the Netherlands.  Certainly, similar levels of cycling to the UK were common until the 60s (ie very high), but they then fell, and have been recovering since the late 70’s, as can be seen above.

This graph shows very clearly that as distance cycled per year increases, safety improves.  However, there is a major confounding factor here – the Dutch changed path in the late 70’s and went all-out to promote cycling.  This led to a program of cycle track building, closing of roads to cars but not cycles etc, building a fit-for-purpose, safe cycling network which will have also had an effect.  So are numbers of cyclists increasing because it’s getting safer to cycle?

Numbers from safety?

It is also commonly argued that it is ‘numbers from safety’ not ‘safety in numbers’; i.e. that more people cycle where conditions are safer to cycle and this accounts for the evidence usually put forward for the S/N effect rather than increasing numbers driving the improvement in safety. It is clearly true that the number one reason that people do not cycle currently in countries such as the UK is a perception of cycling as being dangerous, and the lack of infrastructure to allow people to cycle in safety and comfort. So, is it an increase in numbers cycling that improves safety, or the other way round?

The evidence above cannot differentiate between infrastructure being implemented leading to ‘numbers from safety’ and a true ‘Safety in Numbers’ effect.  What we need is an intervention which will affect cycling numbers in a short period of time without a change in levels of infrastructure.  A perfect example of this is introducing a helmet law and enforcing it – it’s well established that helmet compulsion laws lead to a collapse in numbers cycling.  What happens to safety in the immediate aftermath of these laws being brought in and enforced?

If safety is coming from numbers, independently of infrastructure, we would see that accident rates and deaths per cyclist increase as the number of cyclists decreased.  If this effect was observed over a short time period, where infrastructure cannot be expected to be implemented or taken away, then it is reasonable to assume that it is caused by the change in number of cyclists directly, by whatever mechanism.

1. NZ Helmet Compulsion Law – Introduced 1994

NZ helmetlawsafety

(Graph from here: http://www.cycle-helmets.com/zealand_helmets.html)

This is a fascinating set of data.  Over the course of 3 years, the number of people cycling halves, but the total accident rate stays roughly stable (meaning an increase in risk per person) – and then starts to increase further.  Safety in numbers in reverse – as the number of cyclists fall, the risk per cyclist rises.

2. Australia Helmet Compulsion Law – 1991

(Data lifted from here: http://www.cycle-helmets.com/helmet_analysis.html)


Again, numbers of injuries per cyclist rose as the amount of cycling decreased.  I believe that this is strong evidence that safety does come from numbers of cyclists, as well as infrastructure and other measures.

NB – you’ll note that the data in the two studies above is not in the same units as the graphs at the top.  Both final sets of data measure injuries, not fatalities.  However, I believe that to a good approximation injuries will be proportional to deaths over a short time period – over larger periods of time, as noted above, we are becoming better at keeping people alive; but all of these studies look at periods of time of a decade or less*.


1.  The ‘Safety in Numbers’ effect exists in cycling and as numbers increase, all other things being equal, safety per cyclist improve as shown repeatedly in different studies.

2. There may well be a ‘numbers from safety’ effect where good quality infrastructure and lower speed limits are in place, but safety in numbers exists independently of these measures.

3. The existence of this effect should not be taken as an excuse not to build infrastructure as this is likely to improve safety further.

4.  Helmet compulsion is a poorly considered idea which reduces levels of cycling with downstream public health effects from less people exercising and increases the risk of remaining cyclists having an accident.


My view of how science works is that it doesn’t matter who is making an argument; an argument should stand or fall on its own merits. So don’t take my word for what’s below – I’m happy to have my ideas challenged. Comment away!


*Fatalities may be slightly reduced by the increased wearing of helmets, but this would be a separate effect from looking into Safety in Numbers


Filed under Uncategorized